Sunday, December 27, 2009

Murder in cold blood. Is a new Intifada coming?




We reproduce here an article by the International Socialist League - in Israel-Occupied Palestine. 


The phony "peace process" sponsored by the US is at a deadlock. The Palestinians are worried for the safety of the Mosques in Jerusalem.

Two weeks ago Jewish settlers set a mosque on fire and the Israeli state in spite of its statement that it will do everything to find and punish the criminals did not arrest any one.

Israel has rejected U.S. calls to freeze Jewish settlements on occupied West Bank land where the imperialists have promised a statehood. Benyamin Netanyahu declared a temporary freeze on new constructions in the settlements that does not include Jerusalem but the settlers not only are building new buildings but the Israel government has promised to provide them more money as compensation for the partial temporary "freeze" . Money they will use of course for new buildings. Last week Israel's announced it plans to build 900 new homes in the settlements . Abu Mazen -- fearing the masses , in particular after he supported the Israeli objection to Goldstone's report that angered the Palestinian masses in all Palestine, including in Israel that all of it is stolen land, has refused to yield on this core demand and revive the negotiations.

Last Thursday a settler was shot dead in a guerilla attack. The settlers are armed militia terrorizing the Palestinians. In response the Israeli government sent the army and this force murdered three Palestinians in Nablus , two of them clearly in cold blood plus three young Palestinians in Gaza near the fence that has turned Gaza to a ghetto. A Hamas security source said the three shot in Gaza were apparently civilians collecting scrap metal in an industrial zone near the Israeli border to rebuild their homes destroyed by Israel last year.

In Nablus over 10,000 Palestinians attended the funeral of the three persons who were murdered by Israel. One of the murdered Palestinians has been identified as Anan Subeh, 33, of the Al-Aqsa Martyrs Brigades. The other two Palestinians are Raed a-Sarkaji, 38, and Raghsan Abu Sharah, whose brother was regarded as a top commander with the organization.

During the killing , a-Sarkaji's wife who tried to save his life was shot and wounded and was later transferred to hospital for medical care.

Palestinian security sources report the Israeli troops surrounded the Nablus casbah at around 4:00 A.M. on Saturday. Then, the IDF surrounded one of the homes in the area before proceeding to forcibly enter. The Palestinians had refused Israeli soldiers' calls to surrender.

Israel claims that the Palestinian news agency Ma'an reported that Fatah's Al-Aqsa Martyrs' Brigades claimed responsibility for the killing of the settler. Israel claims as well that the three were members of, Al-Aqsa Martyrs' Brigades. However according to the report in Ma'an:
"An organization calling itself the Imad Mughniya Group and proclaiming affiliation to Fatah's Al-Aqsa Brigades claimed responsibility in an email for the shooting."[i]
Even the Zionist Human Rights organization stated:
"An investigation into an overnight Israel Defense Forces operation in the West Bank city of Nablus early Saturday suggests that Israeli soldiers may have executed two of the three Palestinian militants who were killed, the left wing rights group B'Tselem said Saturday.

In the operation, the IDF killed three Al Aqsa Martyrs Brigades operatives, whom officials said were responsible for a shooting attack on Thursday which killed 40-year-old father of seven Meir Hai of the settlement of Shavei Shomron. The troops surrounded the homes of the three and called for them to exit, and killed them when they refused to surrender.

According to B'Tselem, in two of the three cases the troops behaved as if they were preparing for an execution, not an arrest. Relatives and eyewitnesses told B'Tselem that the two were unarmed and did not attempt to flee, and that the soldiers weren't trying to stop them, but rather shot them from close range once their identity was revealed. There were no witnesses to the shooting of the third man".
Palestinian Authority officials, participated in the funeral procession. The masses called for r retaliation for the death of the three..

"This is another heinous crime on the long list of crimes of the occupation," said Fatah's armed wing in a statement, which promised a speedy and painful response.

The exchange of prisoners is not going any where. Israel has refused to free all the political prisoners on Hamas list. In addition Israel wants to exile about 100 of them and refuse to commit itself not to murder them after their relase.

The imperialists and their local servants are terrified of a new regional Intifadas, and while Abu Mazen made it clear that the PA is against a new Intifada, he is losing control over the Palestinian masses in the West Bank. The only question is what will be the match that will ignite a new intifada.

The Israeli state claim that its criminal actions are justified because of its need to defend the Israeli state. However we do not accept the right of self determination of a settler colonialist society that formed an imperialist state. We defend the right of self determination of only oppressed nations like the Palestinians. In our opinion, following Trotsky line on South Africa is a Palestinian workers state from the river to the sea in the frame work of the socialist federation of the Middle East. This state will ensure the right of return for the Palestinian refugees and the safety of the  Jews who will elect to stay and live in a Palestinian workers state. 

Yossi Schwartz (International Socialist League - in Israel-occupied Palestine).
December 27 2009

Saturday, December 26, 2009

China: FLTI Minority Report on the Current World Situation

-->



The following report is that of the public Minority on China in the FLTI. At the Founding Congress in July 2009 it was agreed that the differences between the Majority and Minority on China would be a public diffference to be debated in front of the worlds working class. The first public exchange of documents was printed in the International Workers Organiser (New Series) No 1 part 1. This is the second exchange beginning with the Minority position, to be followed by the Majority position.
Spanish translation part 1, 2.
-------------------------------------------

“The Truth is Concrete!”

Note: The document says that Russia is a junior imperialist ally of China. This is a CWG position. HWRS did not have as of yet a discussion on Russia. While the HWRS believe that Russia is becoming a sub-imperialism in its “backyard”, e.g. Eastern Europe, the HWRS has not reached a conclusion that Russia is a full blown imperialist country. The HWRS did not have a chance to have a full discussion on this.

--------------------------------------------
This report is written to show that unless the FLTI understands the changes that have taken place in China then we cannot understand their consequences for the world situation, and in particular for the inter-imperialist rivalry in this period of crisis that must lead to wars, revolutions and counter-revolutions. The truth is concrete said Lenin, and the most concrete manifestations of the class struggle today as in Iran, Honduras, or Southern Africa, cannot be fully explained except as the refraction of inter-imperialist rivalry. If we cannot analyze at the concrete level the determinants of class struggle in these situations we will remain theoretically barren, and programmatically weakened in the face of new wars and revolutionary situations.

China, backed by Russia, is the Asian Elephant in the room. We can see the movements around the elephant but cannot explain them unless we see the elephant itself. Against those who say that China is still a socialist state, we have to explain that it has restored capitalism. But against those who say that China is a capitalist semi-colony we have to explain that it is a new imperialist power and that we cannot defend it. While we cannot defend China as an imperialist country, we want to assure the majority that the minority did not change its positions on China. In other words, we still believe that China has a dual character of an emerging imperialist country, while remaining a semi-colony for super-exploitation by the imperialist powers. The minority does not deny the existence of maquiladoras in China, although it is unclear how many of them are owned by Western imperialists and how many are owned by Chinese capitalists. The minority, however, does not think that the maquiladoras are the main drive behind the Chinese economy.

Yet if the US attacks and invades China to transform it into a subordinated semi-colony, the minority without hesitation will defend China against the US imperialism. The only programmatic implications that could develop between the minority and the majority, for example, is in cases when Americans (or their allies) and Chinese troops clash in Iran or Africa over control of oil and raw materials; in other words, over imperialistic spheres of influence and control. Yet, seeing how difficult it is for the US to just maintain its military presence in Iraq and Afghanistan/Pakistan, it is highly unlikely that such wars will develop in the near future.

What do we mean by saying that China still has the character of a semi-colony? In the rest of the article we argue and explain how the Chinese Bourgeoisie was able to remain independent from imperialism and accumulate surplus capital that enables it to become imperialist. In this sense China fulfilled the national tasks of the bourgeois stage of development. Yet the conditions of the proletariat and the peasantry remain the same as in other semi-colonies, and in fact, the proletariat in China is still one of the most super-exploited and oppressed. It is not clear how much better the conditions of the proletariat in the SOEs in comparison to the maquiladoras are. But it is certainly not enough to change its state of super-exploitation. It was the super-exploitation of the Chinese proletariat that allowed the accumulation of surplus capital. Thus in this sense China remains a semi-colony regardless whether its finances and the means of productions are in the hands of the Chinese bourgeoisie or Western imperialists. Thus the minority does not have a different program for the liberation of the Chinese proletariat than the majority’s program. It is the Trotskyist program for the liberation of the most oppressed proletariat and peasantry, and it is essentially the same for China, India and the rest of the semi-colonies; taking into account, of course, national and particular variants.

How to account for this phenomenon of China becoming imperialist? It has to be their history as a deformed workers’ state and degenerated workers’ state (DWS’s) that enables Russia and China to avoid being ‘re-colonized’ or ‘re-divided’ and that allows them to emerge as imperialist powers. If this is correct then our program for China (when it fights for re-division of the world among the imperialist country) must be for its defeat and for its workers to turn all wars in which China is involved as an imperialist power into a civil war in China. With the proviso (as stated above) that an invasion determined to re-divide China, drive it back to the state of a semi-colony and subjugate it militarily to other imperialist forces or a bloc of forces would change the character of a war from inter-imperialist war to a war for imperialist subjugation and require proletarian defense of China.

These and other questions of the expansionary role of China can only be explained by recourse to Lenin’s theory of imperialism. In a global capitalist economy growth is only possible by means of capital accumulation. Expansion overseas into the existing markets or spheres of interest of imperialist powers can only occur at the expense of the existing imperialist powers. It isn’t that China is replacing the US or even France or Japan, but rather that it is expanding at the expense of the weakest imperialists. This has direct effects on the workers and peasants over whose surplus value these powers are fighting. If we cannot explain what is driving China in its expansion, we are theoretically and programmatically weakened in our struggle against the super-exploitation and oppression of all imperialist powers.

The Character of the Current Crisis

The present situation is one of a global economic crisis of overproduction that can only be solved by the capitalists by a massive writing off of trillions of overproduced finance capital, and a massive devaluation of wages through mass sackings and huge wage cuts. Global capitalism is not a single entity. It is a system in which the major capitalist imperialist classes are divided nation by nation and must try to restore their profits by passing as much of their costs as possible onto their imperialist rivals and to their semi-colonies and colonies and ultimately the workers and peasants in those countries. This gives flesh to Lenin’s slogan that the Imperialist epoch is one of crises, wars, revolutions and counter-revolutions.

Since this is a severe global crisis of overproduction, that calls into question the survival of the capitalist system, each imperialist power is forced to attack not only its rivals to unload its costs, but also the living standards of its own wage workers, in particular migrant workers. In this inter-imperialist struggle the strongest imperialist states with the most profitable production come out bigger and stronger, while the less competitive capitalists get weaker and smaller. And of course, whichever imperialist powers come out as the winners, the working class of the whole world ultimately pays with its labor and its lives.

This inter-imperialist struggle must eventually lead to a re-division of the world according to economic power. Lenin was very precise about this:

"The capitalists divide the world, not out of any particular malice, but because the degree of concentration which has been reached forces them to adopt this method in order to obtain profits. And they divide it “in proportion to capital”, “in proportion to strength”, because there cannot be any other method of division under commodity production and capitalism. But strength varies with the degree of economic and political development. In order to understand what is taking place, it is necessary to know what questions are settled by the changes in strength. The question as to whether these changes are “purely” economic or non-economic (e.g., military) is a secondary one, which cannot in the least affect fundamental views on the latest epoch of capitalism. To substitute the question of the form of the struggle and agreements (today peaceful, tomorrow warlike, the next day warlike again) for the question of the substance of the struggle and agreements between capitalist associations is to sink to the role of a sophist". (Imperialism, The Highest Stage of Capitalism, CW 22 p252-3)

The current crisis is one in which the imperialist pecking order is at stake in the struggle to re-divide and plunder the world. The US came to world dominance as a result of WW2 when it gained from the defeat of the Axis powers, occupying Germany and Japan, but also from the relative weakening of Britain and France. But in order to come out the victor the US had to strike a deal with the Soviet Union in which the Stalinist bureaucracy became the executioner of the world revolution in exchange for a buffer zone to protect the Soviet Union. It took another 35 years before the US could restore capitalism to the Soviet Union and China and complete its historic counter-revolutionary mission. But instead of giving US imperialism a new lease on life, China and Russia have turned the tables and emerged as the main potential rivals to US hegemony. This has created huge confusion on the left where the majority of reformists see China as part of a progressive bloc with the Bolivarian states that able to put pressure on US imperialism and drive it to the left. This creates illusions in populist national bourgeoisies and ‘democratic’ imperialism being able to overcome the crisis of capitalism without making the workers pay the price. In the face of this confusion, the new reality of the emergence of China needs to be explained on the basis of the method and theory of Marx, Lenin and Trotsky.

China as an Emerging Global Power

The main difference in the FLTI has arisen over the question of China. How do we explain the dynamic capitalist growth of China facing what is the systemic stagnation in the forces of production globally? Is there something specific to capitalist development in China that allows it to become the main driver of capitalist boom while the rest of the world is in a slump? During the crisis there has been a continued rapid Chinese economic expansion. Moreover this expansion has been at a time when most of the rest of the world was / is in recession.

1) FDI into China has fallen by over 17% for the first eight months of 2009 due to the financial crisis in the US, Japan and the EU.

2) Therefore inward FDI cannot account for China’s growing share of global capital accumulation. Moreover the ‘decoupling’ of China shows that China is not dependent on trade with the US, nor on Treasury bonds.

3) The share of exports in China’s GDP is much smaller than many on the ‘left’ assume at less than 10% and only accounting for around a 25% of China’s GDP growth.

4) If an average of 60% of exports across sectors are produced by foreign owned companies this represents a relatively small part of China’s GDP and less than 20% of its growth. Clearly incoming FDI does not account for more than a small share of China’s rapid growth in recent years, and the fall-off in incoming FDI and trade in 2008 and 2009 coincides with a doubling of China’s overseas FDI in the same period!

The main sources of China’s growth are not FDI but cheap Chinese labour and rising profits:

“Between 1978 and 2007 official mainland China GDP grew at an annual average of 9.7% – a world record. In the last five years China has grown at least 11% annually in real terms, as very high levels of capital investment and a rapidly growing urban population have spurred its tremendous growth… China’s average saving and investment ratios from 1978 until 2007 were nearly 38% of GDP. In 2003 the ratios sky-rocketed, reaching an estimated 51% of GDP last year, while the share of income going to labour fell from 51% in 1991 to 38% in 2006, massively increasing profits.”

Why does China boom amidst a global slump?

Over the past few months, China has capitalized on the financial turmoil that has paralyzed the world’s “developed” economies by stocking up on cheap commodities, weeding out competition to its largest state-run companies, and acquiring even more foreign assets. Indeed, with China’s economic growth projected at an enviable 8% for this year, that country’s government has been able to spend less time promoting immediate growth and liquidity, and more time preparing for the economic renaissance that almost certainly seems to be the Asian giant’s destiny. By exposing Western free-market capitalism, undermining the United States economic clout, and eviscerating commodities prices, the financial crisis has offered China the perfect opportunity to advance its domestic agenda. That agenda begins with the recently unveiled $586 billion stimulus plan – a plan primarily focused on infrastructure. China’s financial institutions have little or no exposure to the toxic subprime assets that spawned this current global crisis. So instead of having to spend hundreds of billions of dollars to bail out its banks, China can choose to develop the stage on which it will display its future economic might. But before its plans for a massive infrastructure overhaul can be realized, China must first load up on the raw materials crucial to its execution.”

The continued growth of China (probably close to 10% in 2009) while the rest of the world, apart from India, is either stagnant or in recession, has been commented on widely on the academic left and fake Trotskyist left.

Those who think that China is state socialist, or mixed capitalist/socialist, put it down to it ability to avoid the worst effects of capitalist crisis. These fall into two camps. First, part of the imperialist bourgeoisie thinks that China is a totalitarian communist country which plays by “different rules” in relation to capitalism and hence is bent on the “Long March to the Oilfield” to challenge and destroy the US as the bastion of free market capitalism. Yet it is clear that a growing and a dominating part of the imperialist bourgeoisie know and recognize the real reality: That China is a rising imperialist power that challenges Western imperialism.

The second are the Bolivarian Bourgeoisie behind Chavez who see China as a major ally of “21st century Socialism”, whose expansion is ‘progressive’ in funding the ‘development’ of globalization from below as in Latin America. Chavez openly states that China and Venezuela are “marching together to socialism”.

On the extreme left of the Bolivarians are the former Trotskyists like the Spartacist current (e.g.IBT) who act as a left cover for the Stalinists by arguing that China remains a DWS despite large steps towards capitalist restoration. For them the expansion of China today is explained as a progressive aspect of the continuation of workers property. China’s expansion is part of the growth of the forces of production in a workers state. It is necessary for a political revolution to prevent China from completing the restoration of capitalism.

Other former Trotskyists like the Australian "Green Left" argue that China is a capitalist semi-colony that wants to maintain its independence from imperialism:

“It is clear that China is now a capitalist country. Yet the imperialists are not totally satisfied. State-owned enterprises remain dominant in certain strategic industrial sectors and in the banking sector. The failure of China to fully apply the neoliberal model meant it could use the state-owned banks to quickly implement stimulus measures after the 2008 global financial crisis. The imperialists want complete privatisation and full access to all areas of the economy. This contributes to the tension between the rulers of China and the US. It helps explain the hypocritical rhetoric from Western politicians and media about the need for “democracy” in China. The Chinese regime wants to maintain a certain degree of independence from imperialism. In the past, it has collaborated with imperialism to attack Third World revolutions, even invading Vietnam in 1979. However, at the moment it has good relations with revolutionary governments in Cuba and Venezuela.”

Other left liberals say that it is China’s powerful central state owned banks and SOEs that have been able to compensate for falling exports by pumping up the domestic economy. Thus China has been able to implement a full-blown Keynesian counter-cyclical policy to protect itself from the global recession while the Obama version of Keynesian stimulus is a Trillion-dollar-plus bailout of the banks and MNCs that further fuels speculation rather than investment in production, and furthers military expenditure. The spending on health reform is held up by a right-wing racist backlash to social spending. The reformist left is envious and argues that the US and EU should nationalize their banks and follow China’s example.

What these positions all point to is the vast capital reserves of China. They are ultimately the result of China’s history as a “post-capitalist” state that allows it to protect itself from exposure to the full forces of the causes of crisis in the global capitalist economy. We can see that the common position here that it is centralized state regulation by the CCP that enables China’s expansion. In the language of Trotskyists, the aspect of China as a DWS that is isolated as the cause of growth is the role of the bureaucracy, not that of workers property.

For revolutionary Trotskyists the bureaucracy is a parasitic caste that cannot develop the forces of production in China. As Trotsky argued the bureaucracy destroys the planned economy because it creates shortages and represses workers resistance to bureaucratic management. The bureaucratic plan must therefore lead to stagnation of the forces of production and thus the basis for the bureaucracy’s privileges. Thus the bureaucracy is forced to restore capitalism and transform itself into a new bourgeoisie or cease to exist as a privileged caste. So China’s phenomenal growth in the last 20 years cannot be the result of state planning under a parasitic caste, but rather rapid capitalist accumulation in the interests of a new national bourgeoisie.

Is China Doomed to be a Big Semi-colony?

Among the Trotskyists who agree that China has restored capitalism many think that China’s expansion via its domestic market and exports serve the interests of imperialist firms producing for export in China. The Australian Green Left puts it this way:

“China has increasingly become the imperialist West’s main workshop for the production of cheap consumer goods, draining China’s energy, water and other natural resources, and polluting its environment. Chinese-owned companies’ investments in Africa are largely driven by a basic agenda of seeking fuel and minerals inputs for the production in China of manufactures by Chinese firms working as subcontractors for big Western corporations, with the bulk of the profits going to the latter. In 2002, exports by Chinese subsidiaries of First World corporations accounted for 25.8% of China’s exports — up from 20.3% in 1997, according to the World Investment Report 2006. According to the WIR 2006, the value added in China by the subsidiaries of First World corporations amounted to US$103.6 billion, and their pre-tax profits from such operations totaled $22.7 billion. According to the November 29, 2004, China Business Weekly, the US-based Wal-Mart corporation, the world’s biggest retailer, bought $15 billion worth of products from China, mostly through a network of 5000 China-based firms. Today, Wal-Mart alone accounts for one-third of the $60 billion in manufactures exported from China. No matter how big a share of the world’s low-technology processing and assembly work China takes on, the imperialist corporations will retain their monopoly of superior technology in the decisive industries. And while Chinese companies are becoming significant investors in some African countries, most of the continent’s industries are dominated by foreign direct investment (FDI) from US and European corporations. As the February 10 New York Times noted, “China is not yet an overwhelming presence in Africa. The juggernaut image aside, China imports less African oil, invests less money and spends less on aid than does the United States or Europe.” According to the most recent UN figures, total FDI holdings in Africa in 2005 were worth $96 billion, of which European firms accounted for 61%, US firms 20%, Asian firms 8% and South African firms 2%. Of the $29 billion of FDI that went into Africa in 2005, only $1.2 billion (4.1%) came from China." Green Left Weekly issue #701 7 March 2007.

While this is partly true (based on 2006 data that is already outdated) it cannot account for the fact that China does not fit the profile of a semi-colony. Semi-colonies have: 1) chronic trade deficits, 2) capital deficits, 3) huge national debts, and 4) relatively low growth rates as surplus value is pumped out of the economy by imperialism. Compared with Mexico which has all of these features, China is very different. Despite the pumping out of surplus value from China by imperialist FDI nonetheless this is a relatively small part of the surplus value produced in China. China’s rapid growth has created a massive trade surplus, capital surplus and annual GDP growth in excess of 10%. The argument that China’s $800 billion in US Treasury Bonds exposes it to US domination is ludicrous. Japan is second to China with $725 billion in T-bonds. It is subject to the same threat of dollar devaluation. Japan may be dominated by the US but does that make Japan a semi-colony? A rapid devaluation of the dollar would hurt China but that is unlikely, and in the long run China as creditor will be the winner according to prominent bourgeois commentator Nourial Roubini:

"China is a creditor country with large current account surpluses, a small budget deficit, much lower public debt as a share of G.D.P. than the United States, and solid growth. And it is already taking steps toward challenging the supremacy of the dollar. Beijing has called for a new international reserve currency in the form of the International Monetary Fund’s special drawing rights (a basket of dollars, euros, pounds and yen). China will soon want to see its own currency included in the basket, as well as the renminbi used as a means of payment in bilateral trade…If China and other countries were to diversify their reserve holdings away from the dollar — and they eventually will — the United States would suffer. We have reaped significant financial benefits from having the dollar as the reserve currency. In particular, the strong market for the dollar allows Americans to borrow at better rates. We have thus been able to finance larger deficits for longer and at lower interest rates, as foreign demand has kept Treasury yields low. We have been able to issue debt in our own currency rather than a foreign one, thus shifting the losses of a fall in the value of the dollar to our creditors. Having commodities priced in dollars has also meant that a fall in the dollar’s value doesn’t lead to a rise in the price of imports…This decline of the dollar might take more than a decade, but it could happen even sooner if we do not get our financial house in order. The United States must rein in spending and borrowing, and pursue growth that is not based on asset and credit bubbles. For the last two decades America has been spending more than its income, increasing its foreign liabilities and amassing debts that have become unsustainable. A system where the dollar was the major global currency allowed us to prolong reckless borrowing."

The decline of the Dollar in fact reflects the decline of US imperialism. The bankers and the oil barons in the Middle East do not trade exclusively with petro-dollars anymore. Petro-dollars are indeed no longer the god for oil buying and selling, and US competitors are in a “united front” against the petrodollars for now:

“In the most profound financial change in recent Middle East history, Gulf Arabs are planning – along with China, Russia, Japan and France – to end dollar dealings for oil, moving instead to a basket of currencies including the Japanese yen and Chinese yuan, the euro, gold and a new, unified currency planned for nations in the Gulf Co-operation Council, including Saudi Arabia, Abu Dhabi, Kuwait and Qatar."

“Secret meetings have already been held by finance ministers and central bank governors in Russia, China, Japan and Brazil to work on the scheme, which will mean that oil will no longer be priced in dollars.”

As noted already, despite falling FDI during the current crisis, despite the devaluation of China’s massive dollar reserves, China’s expansion continues. China is not only boosting its growth by the half-trillion stimulus to domestic spending. In the middle of the world recession it has made a “great leap forward” in foreign investment; i.e. capital export, the critical characteristic of imperialism. What this means is that China has not only sufficient accumulated surpluses to spend on domestic infrastructure, social spending on the unemployed etc., it has accumulated surpluses in the profits of the massive SOEs and in its Sovereign Capital Fund that enable it to rapidly expand its foreign investment, either as outward FDI in foreign companies, such as Joint Ventures like that with Venezuela for oil production, and loans for oil in a number of countries. As we shall see below this is Chinese finance capital, not the FDI of other imperialist countries using China as a proxy in capital re-export:

“In 2002, China’s outbound investment was just $2.5 billion. By 2007, the figure had reached $18.6 billion, which more than doubled in 2008 to $52.2 billion. Standard Chartered estimates that the tally this February alone was $65 billion. The bank predicted that Chinese outward FDI in 2009 would hit $150-$180 billion—compared to inward FDI of $80-100 billion. According to the UN World Investment Report 2008, only the US, UK, Germany, France and Spain invested more than $100 billion abroad in 2007. In 2008, China’s cumulative overseas FDI was just 0.6 percent of the world’s total, but it could rise rapidly. China has the world’s highest rate of savings (about 50 percent of GDP, compared to around 25 percent of Japan), large current account surpluses (more than 10 percent of GDP in 2008, compared to Japan’s record high of 4.3 percent in 1983) and the world’s largest currency reserves of $US1.95 trillion.”

In other words China has turned the crisis of US and EU finance capital and the global recession into an opportunity to export its own finance capital and to establish imperialist spheres of influence. As a result, China is now entering directly into competition with the existing imperialist powers as an emerging imperialist in particular posing a major challenge to the US, the UK, Germany and France and Japan. What accounts for this amazing performance when the rest of the imperialist states are in recession or stagnating?

The answer can be found by going back to the salient point that the secret of China’s “success” rests in its highly centralized state banks and SOEs which can act to take advantage of the global recession. And while we argue that China is no longer a DWS we say its ‘advantage’ is a legacy of China’s history as a deformed workers’ state (DWS). In other words if China had not been a DWS it could never have become a dynamic capitalist country. It would have been fated to be divided and ruled by imperialism from the early 20th century to the early 21st century. Like all other semi-colonies, China would never have been in the position to accumulate sufficient capital to force its ruling class to export surplus finance capital and emerge as a new imperialist power.

This would be what Trotskyists would expect on the basis of Lenin’s theory of imperialism which in the epoch of imperialism – capitalism’s highest stage – spoke of imperialist powers competing to re-divide the world. New imperialist powers could only arise on the basis of expanding into parts of the world as yet not dominated by other imperialist powers. Once the world was divided, imperialists could only advance by re-dividing it at the expense of other imperialist powers. Japan did this at the expense of other imperialist powers, mainly Britain and France. And Japan was made to pay the price for its expansion and defeated in war and subordinated to the US. So while imperialist powers may win or lose in imperialist wars, there is general agreement that there is no possibility of colonies and semi-colonies oppressed by one or other imperialist power transforming themselves by means of national revolutions into imperialist powers. Therefore, if one ignores the special characteristics of the former DWS’s one could easily conclude that in the epoch of imperialism there is no room for new imperialist powers to emerge. Two World Wars were proof of the correctness of this theory.

To characterize China today as imperialist appears to contradict the logic of Lenin’s theory of imperialism which states that no colony or semi-colony can make a national democratic revolution and emerge as a new imperialist power. However, if it can be proved that China did make its national revolution and win independence as a DWS and that the restoration of capitalism did not cause it to lose that independence then there is no contradiction with Lenin’s theory. We would find that the essence of his theory explains the apparent anomaly that a former workers state can do what is otherwise impossible – become a new imperialist power.

The Law of Value (What the Spartacist Currents Ignore)

What distinguishes the DWSs from capitalist colonies or semi-colonies is its relative isolation and independence from the global capitalist market. Thus the DWSs have been “partitioned” by revolutions that overthrew capitalist social relations putting them outside the imperialist spheres of influence. Of course their isolation means they don’t escape capitalist imperialism entirely. It oppresses them indirectly by stopping them from developing the forces of production by means of new technology. But by definition DWSs are isolated from the direct effects of the law of value. The prices of production of state produced goods and services are not determined by the value of labor power as is the case in the capitalist market. Prices are determined by a plan.

Whether or not that plan is under the control of workers democracy or a bureaucratic caste makes a big difference. In the former case prices are used to signal the amount of necessary labor that workers democratically decide should be used to produce goods and services to meet their needs. In the latter case labor is allocated to produce goods and services that favor the luxury consumption of the bureaucracy and not that of the needs of workers. The forces of production stagnate and are relative to a democratic plan destroyed (wasted). But in both cases the planned economy develops the forces of production to a greater degree than is possible in a semi-colony where production is controlled by a division of labor imposed by imperialism. Such a planned economy requires a centralized production process and a centralized state. Hence the origins of the strong central state and state owned enterprises (SEOs) in the DWSs.

China’s revolution in 1949 was a national revolution led by Stalinist army of peasants in isolation from the working class that was forced to go on to become a (deformed) socialist revolution because the weak national bourgeoisie was aligned with imperialism and incapable of completing the national task. But from the outset, the ordinary peasants and workers never had control of the revolution, leading to the form of workers state that emerged being ‘deformed’ or bureaucratized from its birth. The planned economy under the control of the party bureaucracy developed the forces of production beyond that of any semi-colony but never to the point that they could match that of capitalist imperialism. Added to the bureaucratic plan, the isolation of the economy from the world market prevented it from acquiring new technology to increase the productivity of labor other than by increasing its intensity.

The resulting stagnation meant that the privileges of the bureaucracy who lived a parasitic existence on the labor of the workers were threatened. This led the Communist Party to reintroduce private property rights (a sort of NEP) in agriculture to stimulate production and hence its share of the surplus product. Thus the Law of Value (LOV) was planted in the countryside. The LOV spread to industry and commerce and caused a full blown restoration of capitalism around 1992. As Trotsky had already predicted, the form of capitalism that is restored in a DWS will likely be a state capitalism that uses the existing state machinery and SOEs to reproduce the production of surplus value and profit. It does this by allowing the LOV (the market) to determine prices as opposed to the planning process. China’s accession to the WTO in 2001 marked its full entry into the world capitalist economy.

To recap: China as a DWS ‘partitioned’ itself from the capitalist economy and developed the forces of production internally beyond that possible in a semi-colony oppressed by imperialism. Yet its isolation led to economic stagnation and the Communist Party planned the restoration of capitalism to stimulate growth and the transformation of the parasitic bureaucracy dependent on their control of the plan into a new national bourgeoisie in a restored capitalist economy. Thus, on this argument, capitalism that is restored in a former workers state has special characteristics which are critical in allowing it to escape the fate of a capitalist semi-colony and to emerge as a new imperialist power.

China’s legacy was therefore a strong centralized state and massive SOEs under the control of a strong and relatively united new national bourgeoisie. China’s re-entry into the capitalist world economy was managed in stages so that the new bourgeoisie retained its independence from all imperialist powers. As the imperialists sought to use China as a semi-colony to re-locate their maquiladoras using cheap Chinese labor, the Chinese ruling class retained control of the key state sectors of the economy and restricted the freedom of entry of FDI, and in particular of the big imperialist banks. Incoming FDI was encouraged as a means of driving the development of Chinese capitalism without the national bourgeoisie losing control over the ownership and control of the means of production. The success of China in this transition is now viewed enviously by the Russian leadership which opened up its economy to imperialism and now wants to recover control over the economy by learning the lessons of China’s strong centralized state transition.

“In truth, the Russians express no desire to return to Communism as a far-reaching Marxist-Leninist ideology, whether the Soviet version or the much attenuated one in Beijing. What they admire, it seems, is the Chinese ability to use a one-party system to keep tight control over the country while still driving significant economic growth. It is a historical turnabout that resonates, given that the Chinese Communists were inspired by the Soviets, before the two sides had a lengthy rift. For the Russians, what matters is the countries’ divergent paths in recent decades. They are acutely aware that even as Russia has endured many dark days in its transition to a market economy, China appears to have carried out a fairly similar shift more artfully. The Russians also seem almost ashamed that their economy is highly dependent on oil, gas and other natural resources, as if Russia were a third world nation, while China excels at manufacturing products sought by the world.”

In other words, US and other imperialist powers could not ‘repartition’ or ‘redivide’ a restored capitalist China as their own spheres of interest. The new Chinese bourgeoisie retained control of the national economy and could use the centralized state to monopolize the process of capital accumulation on the same basis as the existing imperialist powers. That is, it operated on the basis of the law of value which sets prices in terms of labor power, but in reality it is extracting super-profits and monopoly rent on its own account – the defining feature of imperialism. Let us expand on this point.

Super Profits and Monopoly Rent

For Lenin imperialism is characterized by monopoly which in the last analysis extracts super-profits in the form of monopoly rent. Marx defined monopoly rent as the difference between the price of production and market price where the latter is determined by a few firms that act as a cartel, or trust i.e. a monopoly. This concept simplifies our understanding of super-profits arising from so-called cheap labor as well as the plundering of raw materials and energy sources. The price of production consists of labor costs, raw materials etc., plus average profits where competition allows a redistribution of surplus-value. That is, in the epoch of competitive capitalism, the price of production reflects competition where average profits result from a process of the equalization of profits from the least efficient producers to the more efficient, given that there is sufficient demand.

Imperialist monopoly ends competition at the level of the market as a few firms control the prices by preventing the ability of more efficient firms to undercut their price. Prices of production now include not the average profit resulting from equalization but a monopoly price. The ‘equalizing’ of profits is done by “fixing” the price in advance of production and not by the market after production. This is why Lenin observed that the imperialist epoch is dominated by monopolies where a few large firms – cartels, trusts, monopolies – set the world prices in various sectors of production such as oil, steel, railways etc.

A short sidetracking is necessary here to distinguish between imperialist monopoly and the so-called monopoly of state planning in the DWSs. While the central state apparatus may in fact by formally the same, as the Communist Party is like a giant monopoly firm planning, or fixing, prices, the law of value separates out these two forms in their essence. Ideally socialist monopoly (i.e. in a workers’ democratic plan) sets prices without any reference to the law of value. Prices are just a means of allocating labor to different branches of production to meet collectively determined needs. Capitalist monopoly however, determines super-profits by calculating monopoly rent as value in excess of the ‘real’ market price of production set by the law of value. By ‘real’ we mean that monopoly looks for the lowest labor and raw material costs (this is the point of investing FDI in colonies and semi-colonies) so that the excess of monopoly price of production over the real price of production (assuming competition) is a great as possible. Nevertheless, when it comes to the changing class character of the central state, it is a relatively simple matter to switch the state monopoly over the allocation of workers labor in a Deformed Workers State like China to the monopoly of value produced in a capitalist economy.

If the above argument is correct, China has been able to use its legacy as a DWS to convert its centralized state apparatus into a monopoly capitalist state to escape the trap of semi-colonial partition, oppression and super-exploitation by the existing imperialist powers. It has done this by monopolising land which remains nationalised, and by heavily regulating FDI in terms of both relative and absolute share of value produced in China. Thus the Joint Equity Ventures law of 2001 (No. 48) states the basic criteria on which FDI enters China. FDI operates under ‘business licenses’ under Chinese law and can be “nationalised with payment of compensation”. Generally the FDI share in JVs is limited to less than 25%. However the Foreign Investors law of 2000 allows 100% FDI in companies that meet the criteria of “economic cooperation”, “technological exchange” and “export orientation”.

The state retains a monopoly control over the key sectors of industry, energy, and banking via its State Owned Enterprises and State Banks. Typically the SEOs do not pass on their profits to the state but accumulate them for further reinvestment. Does FDI share in this bounty? The share of incoming FDI in SOEs is limited to around 20%. The fact that FDI does not control the SOEs is confirmed by attempts to block them from being taken over by established US and other monopoly firms. For example, the third ranking oil and gas SOE and biggest offshore operator, CNOOC had its bid to buy the US oil major Unocal in 2005 rejected as US politicians feared the loss of a US oil major Unocal (which has the key role in the planned pipeline across Afghanistan) to a 100% China state owned SEO.

Interestingly one conservative US commentator pointed to the hypocrisy of this rejection. Any state monopoly support gained by CNOOC in the process of this acquisition would be matched by big US oil corporations, including Chevron, which was the preferred buyer of Unocal at a lower price. It seems that the Chinese SOEs do not “play by different rules” but by the same rules of state monopoly imperialism!

The big international banks do not own China. The biggest ‘Western’ stake is the Bank of America’s 20% shareholding in the China Construction Bank. [Since been reduced to 16% as BOA needed the cash!] But of course this cannot be a controlling shareholding in a predominantly state-owned bank

“CCB, with total assets of approximately $1.1 trillion, is the second largest bank in China.2 The government of China owns approximately 57.0 percent of CCB's shares.3 Bank of America Corporation4 and Temasek Holdings, a sovereign wealth fund owned by the government of Singapore, own 19.1 and 5.7 percent, respectively, of the shares of CCB. No other shareholder owns more than 5 percent of CCB's shares.5

China accumulates its capital on its own account and has a massive Sovereign Wealth Fund that has no need for large borrowings from international banks. It has a 10% share of Morgan Stanley and looks to buy up to 49%. It has shares in other banks and equity funds such as a 10% stake in Blackstone private equity fund. As noted China is a large US creditor with around US$800 billion in Treasury bonds and other securities which creates a potentially large sovereign fund for FDI.

Is China just a giant maquiladora for foreign imperialists? No. China was never just a maquiladora. 

(1) We have seen that exports only account for around 25% of China’s GDP growth.
(2) Nearly half of FDI in China originates in Hong Kong and much of it is ‘round-tripping” Chinese capital taking advantage of tax breaks for exporters. [The proportion is unknown, but foreign companies do not gain any advantage by hiding their FDI as originating in Hong Kong e.g. the next largest source of FDI is Taiwan. The recent lifting of tax breaks may see Chinese capital round-tripping through Hong Kong cease].
(3) While US, EU and Japanese imperialism benefits from FDI and cheap Chinese imports, its profitability comes from tax breaks, and cheap labor, rather than any advantages from buying Chinese inputs.
(4) Chinese manufacturers do not sell inputs cheaply to foreign exporters. A recent analysis showed that China’s return from FDI in copper mining in the Democratic Republic of Congo was higher than that of the giant US mining firm Freeport.
(5) The super-profits of the FDI manufacturing export sector in China are therefore dependent on cheap labor and tax breaks that do not represent a major drain on the super-profits of Chinese state monopoly capitalism.

If it were not the case then how do we explain the rapid capital accumulation in China? This drain on China’s potential super-profits may be greater with FDI in Joint Ventures (JV) where foreign investors have an equal share and produce for the China market. For example General Motors has as 50/50 partnership with the SOE Shanghai Automotive Industry Corporation. But this profit sharing is a tradeoff for long-run benefits flowing from “spillovers” in new technology that result from JVs in the domestic market. Ironically, the GM parent company is currently 61% owned by the US Treasury, 17% by the UAW union, and 11% by the Canadian state following a Chapter 11 bankruptcy! Thus the strong growth of GM expected in China in 2009 will help rescue GM in the USA but it will also boost the share of profits by the SOE partner SAIC.

While this type of JV may increase the share of FDI profits by producing for the domestic market, it is still a relatively small share of total FDI and does not prove that China is a semi-colony. On the contrary, GM and SAIC have set up a JV to produce autos together in India.

Two Opposed Imperialist Blocs

The ability of China to ride out this depression by using their overproduced capital in the form of state sovereign funds and SOE surpluses to invest in expansion of FDI into energy, cash swaps for oil etc in Asia, Africa and Latin America, proves that they are in a strong position to compete successfully in displacing bankrupted imperialist powers whose finance sectors have had to be bailed out by massive state debt creation. This means that the greatest points of conflict as the imperialists jockey for position during this crisis will be between the US imperialist bloc and the new bloc based on the emerging Chinese imperialism.

The rise of China (backed by Russia) is not only a problem for the US, it is also a big problem for the other imperialist powers, in particular Britain, France, Germany, Japan, Spain and Australia because these are more or less subordinated to the US and are the ones most likely to lose out in the rise of China and Russia. But the old rivalry between Europe and the US has not vanished. It is not clear what France and Germany will do as the tension between the US and China rises. France has a temporary pact with the US in regard to Iran, while it is making deals with China in Venezuela. Germany is a wild card. It appears to be in the US camp, while it is making deals with Russia behind the US’s back. Germany just made a deal with Russia for the pipeline that will go directly from Russia to Germany. It is the The new Nord Stream pipeline that will be traveling more than 750 miles underwater, from Vyborg, Russia, to Greifswald, Germany, bypassing the former Soviet and satellite states, thus it will give Russia a separate supply line to the West, in particularly to Germany. According to the New York Times: 

“Currently, Russian gas has to be piped through Eastern Europe to reach Western Europe. If Russia shuts off the gas to pressure a neighbor in the east, it is felt in the more powerful, wealthier countries to the west, where it touches off loud protests."

The new Nord Stream pipeline will change that equation. By traveling more than 750 miles underwater, from Vyborg, Russia, to Greifswald, Germany, bypassing the former Soviet and satellite states, it will give Russia a separate supply line to the west.

“As a result, many security experts and Eastern European officials say, Russia will be more likely to play pipeline politics with its neighbors.”

So gas will flow to Germany without going through the Eastern European countries i.e. Ukrainel etc. Germany will have a special deal with Russia in regard to the supply of gas, while Russia can use the old pipeline to control its backyard (cut off supply to Eastern Europe if necessary while Germany can still get it). Even though now most European imperialists line up behind the US, that can change and to some degree it is already changing. Germany always had close relations with Russia, and as the tension between all imperialist countries increase there is no reason why Germany will not join the China-Russia bloc. As overproduction becomes more and more acute, it will difficult to predict which side French imperialism will take. At the moment it defends its interests in Iran by lining up behind the US, but at the same time China’s CNPC is part of a JV with Total (France) in Venezuela. Ultimately it is not our business to predict exactly how the different imperialist blocs will line up against each other in the future.

While the US has rejected Chinese SOE bids for US firms, [e.g. Unocol] China has increased investment in Australia [e.g. Rio Tinto and BHP] where Chinese ownership could see Australian imperialism become subordinated to China rather than the US. Japan, currently the No. 2 imperialist economy by GDP, is being overtaken by China.

“For years, Japan has been readying itself for the day that it is eclipsed economically by China. But as a result of the global slowdown, Japan’s difficulty in managing its economy and China’s rise — on vivid display Thursday as Beijing celebrated the 60th anniversary of the founding of the People’s Republic — that day may come sooner than anyone predicted. Though recent wild currency swings could delay the reckoning, many economists expect Japan to cede its rank as the world’s second-largest economy sometime next year, as much as five years earlier than previously forecast. At stake are more than regional bragging rights: the reversal of fortune will bring an end to a global economic order that has prevailed for 40 years, with ramifications across arenas from trade and diplomacy to, potentially, military power. China’s rise could accelerate Japan’s economic decline as it captures Japanese export markets, and as Japan’s crushing national debt increases and its aging population grows less and less productive — producing a downward spiral.”

This means that the crisis is one that will see some imperialist powers decline and others fight for their survival, so the stakes are high and the consequences for the exploited masses are huge. Each imperialist power in attempting to force its rivals into submission also drives down the wages and conditions of its own proletariat and enlists them as cannon fodder in their military adventures. It is the weakest imperialists that have to pass on the highest costs to their own workers or risk extinction. Thus Britain, Spain, Denmark and Australia along with numerous other semi-colonial and client states offered troops to the US invasion and occupation of Iraq in the hope that the US could protect their imperialist status. Japan has had so-called ‘non-combatant’ troops in Iraq and has provided logistic support for the war in Afghanistan. France and Germany refused to participate in the Iraqi war. Germany has also been reluctant to put frontline troops in Afghanistan, while France has only just rejoined NATO as a full member after 30 years even though it has had around 2000 combat troops in Afghanistan since 2000.

However, there is no guarantee that these US rivals will gain any advantage or that the US junior imperialist partners will survive by selling the lives of their soldiers. It was no accident that another minor imperialist power subordinate to the US, Greece, facing bankruptcy, tried to impose a massive austerity program on its workers at the end of 2008 and was then faced with an uprising. It is French imperialism, now weakened and in a temporary alliance with the US, that has lagged behind in its market reforms which means that to restore its competitiveness it has to attack the past gains of its workers and finds itself facing strikes and occupations at home, and semi-insurrections in the Antilles. Despite a polite non-aggression pact, which saw France observe the US sanctions on Iran, the rivalry between France and the US goes on in proxy fronts as we saw in Madagascar, a former French colony, that came under the influence of South Korea, a proxy of Japan and the US, but was met with an insurrection in which the workers, farmers and ranks of the military united. Similarly the rivalry between the US and Russia over control of the oil rich Caucasus sparked a war over South Ossetia and Abkhazia at the expense of the people on both sides used as cannon fodder in this war. In Latin America, France’s Total is now in JV with Chinese SOEs to develop Orinoco oil in Venezuela, thus the temporary pack between the US and France can fall apart.

But, while every lesser imperialist power is now fighting to retain its share of the world market, the US has the most to lose from the rise of China backed by Russia. This is what explains Obama’s military aggression towards Afghanistan, his bombing of Pakistan, his backing of Africom in Ghana, his keeping the pressure on Iran, his complicity in the US backed coup in Honduras (Cuba is of course a big factor here), etc. All of these are instances of the US using its vast military superiority to stake out territory so that it can command spheres of influence that are vital for future supplies of raw materials – in particular oil, gas and minerals. The US finds that it is not its historic rivals, now reduced to secondary powers that are its chief rivals, but China backed by Russia. Instead of breaking up the old Soviet Union and Republic or China, these states remain relatively intact under strong military state capitalist regimes. They retain control over their former territories as DWSs that comprise most of Central Asia (or Eurasia), which is rapidly becoming the biggest battleground between the two imperialist blocs.

The Battle for Central Asia

Thus the Middle East is the US launching platform for Central Asia and the struggle to take over the huge sphere of influence of Russia and China over the former Soviet republics of the USSR and the Autonomous regions of China: Xinjian Uygur, Ningxia Huia, and Gansu and Shaanxi Provinces. And it is over control of these vital raw materials that we can expect new imperialist wars, in particular proxy wars, is in the making. This is because China and Russia have been able to keep control over the former territories of the their respective DWSs.

The key to the battle for Eurasia is its oil and gas. The Brazilian journalist Pepe Escobar has a series on “Pipelineistan” in the Asia Times. One article details the huge political investment of the US and its allies in the only pipeline out of Central Asia not controlled by China or Russia:

“History may judge it as one of the capital moves of the 21st century's New Great Game: May 25, the day high-quality Caspian light crude started flowing through the Caucasus toward the Mediterranean in Turkey. The Baku-Tbilisi-Ceyhan pipeline (BTC) - conceived by the US as the ultimate Western escape route from dependence on oil from the Persian Gulf - is finally in business… This BTC state slices Azerbaijan in half from east to west, then slices Georgia in half almost from east to west, before taking a dip south, bypassing secessionist Ajaria and slicing Turkish Anatolia diagonally from the northeast toward the south. The founding stone is at British Petroleum's (BP's) gleaming terminal at Sangachal, half an hour along the Caspian south of Baku. The state is 44 meters wide, snaking 1,767 kilometers across three countries, two of those (Azerbaijan and Georgia) extremely volatile, and the other (Turkey) faces potential trouble from dispossessed Kurds. To understand the scope and ambition of BTC, one must visit Villa Petrolea, the Baku headquarters of BP. The BTC's major shareholders are BP (30.1%) and the Azerbaijani state oil company SOCAR (25%), followed by Unocal (US, 8.9%), Statoil (Norway, 8.71%), Turkish Petroleum (6.53%), ENI (Italy, 5%), TotalFinaElf (France, 5%), Itochu (Japan, 3.4%), ConocoPhillips (US, 2.5%), Inpex (Japan, 2.5%) and Delta Hess (a joint venture of Saudi Delta Oil with American Amerada, 2.36%). BP has invested at least $15 billion in the country (exploration, exploitation, pipeline construction)… Azerbaijan, Georgia and Turkey were all desperate to finish BTC on time. Turkey owes a fortune to the International Monetary Fund. Georgia survives thanks largely to American handouts. Azerbaijan at least set up a state oil fund to use oil revenues to the benefit of future generations…In terms of no-holds-barred power politics and oil geopolitics, BTC is the real deal - a key component in the US's overall strategy of wrestling the Caucasus and Central Asia away from Russia - and bypassing Iranian oil and gas routes. Kazakh President Nursultan Nazarbaev, for instance, has just announced that Kazakh crude will also flow through the BTC before 2010. He even proposed to add Aktau - the Kazakh Caspian oil Mecca - to a new acronym (ABTC?). It's interesting to remember that BP always denied that it needs Kazakh oil to fill its pipeline…Anyway, what really matters is positioning in the New Great Game. The Caucasus, the Caspian and Central Asia are up for grabs. European customers for Azeri (and Kazakh) oil and gas might rely on BTC for some of their supply. But the Russian counterpunch will come: President Vladimir Putin will not cease to seduce the European Union with loads of Russian, Caspian oil - plus strong protection - in return for loads of European Union investment."

Today the most immediate war threat in the battle or Central Asia involves US/Israel and Iran/China/Russia in the Middle East and Iran. Behind the fiction that Iran is breaking an agreement over nuclear arms is the reality that Iran has one of the largest reserves of oil and gas in the world. More from Escobar’s tales of “Pipelineistan”:

“Every time I've visited Iran, energy analysts stress the total "interdependence of Asia and Persian Gulf geo-ecopolitics". What they mean is the ultimate importance to various great and regional powers of Asian integration via a sprawling mass of energy pipelines that will someday, somehow, link the Persian Gulf, Central Asia, South Asia, Russia and China. The major Iranian card in the Asian integration game is the gigantic South Pars natural gas field (which Iran shares with Qatar). It is estimated to hold at least 9% of the world's proven natural gas reserves. As much as Washington may live in perpetual denial, Russia and Iran together control roughly 20% of the world's oil reserves and nearly 50% of its gas reserves. Think about that for a moment. It's little wonder that, for the leadership of both countries as well as China's, the idea of Asian integration, of the Grid, is sacrosanct."

What is more Iran is hostile to the US world domination and its Middle East Gendarme Israel, and is increasingly aligned economically and politically to China and Russia. Some of the reasons for this growing alliance are spelled out here. So if it is not Iran’s main allies, China and Russia who are the main rivals of the US and EU imperialists competing for Iran’s oil and gas, who is it? France and Japan have complied with US pressure to back off from actively pursuing its interests in Iran. France has a large FDI stake in Iran so it cannot afford to let its rivals steal a march. Nor can Japan afford to allow China to push it out of Iran’s gas reserves. So both France and Japan are backing the US in its global battle to block China’s rapid emergence so as to protect their respective stakes.

Who is left? Germany? Germany’s main interest in Iran is to get an alternate supply of gas via Turkey in the Nabasco pipeline due for completion in 2015. On the other hand, Germany agreed to The new Nord Stream pipeline that will be traveling more than 750 miles underwater, from Vyborg, Russia, to Greifswald, Germany. But even though Germany is an important client of Russian gas, Germany also competes with Russia. Russia has agreed to buy all gas not sold to EU, with India (pipeline planned across Baluchistan) with China (3rd largest customer) and Japan for Iranian gas supplies in the future. Germany’s FDI in Iran is behind that of China. During 2001-2007 French companies were the leading investors in Iran at $30.2 billion, followed by China at $29.5 billion, Germany at $26 billion, Italy at $23.7 billion, and Japan at $18.3 billion. But clearly Germany is one of many competitors who are losing out to the growing influence of China in Iran. Because of the sanctions China became Iran's number one trading partner in 2005 after four consecutive years as number two.

Today China has become the major partner in developing Iran’s gas production and distribution and is stepping up the scale of its FDI in Iran which totals around US$120 billion. One of the incentives for the Iranian capitalists to welcome China with open arms is the Chinese’s promise to build oil refineries in Iran. This is a huge winning card in the competition between Europe and China over the control of oil in Iran. Western imperialism kept Iran under its thumb by preventing the construction of oil refineries in Iran. China is willing to do it, which makes China irresistible to the Iranian capitalists. 

“In June, China National Petroleum signed a $5 billion deal to develop the South Pars natural gas field in Iran. In July, Iran invited Chinese companies to join a $42.8 billion project to build seven oil refineries and a 1,019-mile trans-Iran pipeline. And in August, almost as the Americans arrived in China, Tehran and Beijing struck another deal, this time for $3 billion, that will pave the way for China to help Iran expand two more oil refineries.”

We cannot understand the standoff over Iran’s nuclear weapons without recognizing the Chinese elephant in the room. Iran is surrounded by US client regimes in Iraq, Afghanistan, and Pakistan. Iran can only resist the US because it has the backing of Russia and China. Everybody knows this to be the modern version of the “great game” to take control of Eurasia away from China and Russia. China is the economic powerhouse, and Russia is the nuclear arsenal. Iran has agreed to send its enriched uranium to Russia to be turned into fuel hoping to dodge severe sanctions. China is not going to obey the US and pull out of Iran like France or Germany might. It works closely with Russia in trying to water down US sanctions in the Security Council.

Like Russia, China is opposed to tougher sanctions. Moreover, in Iraq, China with BP has won a big concession to extract oil in Rumaila. China now risks a rift with the US in the Middle East. And the US is spreading its 'war on terror' to Yemen to dominate trade flows in the region.

The Battle for Africa

A second arena where competition for oil and minerals looms large is Africa. The major rivals are no longer Britain and France but the US and China. Britain and France still have huge investments in Africa and also stand to lose out to China. But the main losers will be the minor imperialists like Portugal and Belgium whose spheres of interest are being taken over by China. Playing supporting roles are the Russians on the side of China, and Israel on the side of the US. A new scramble for Africa is well under way. Each rival attempts to use its economic and political influence to win over the national bourgeoisies as junior partners in their spheres of influence.

In Angola, China has replaced Portuguese imperialism which abandoned Angola in 1975 (China’s biggest trading partner; Angola is the biggest oil supplier to China, as also to the US. This is a hot spot in Africa where US / China rivalry will surface first. Angola will replace Nigeria as main oil producer, dependent on China FDI in oil. This is reflected in WSJ article (below) which recounts the attempts led by Chevron etc to regain control over Angola’s oil. It also explains the PR visit by Hilary Clinton. The IMF after years of neglect just loaned 1B to Angola. Thus the rivalry over China’s biggest stake in Africa is heating up!

In Nigeria, China has big oil investments, rail investments, and most recently a deal to rival or displace the oil majors in a 49% JV with the Nigerian National Petroleum Corporation (NNPC) worth $50bn. This is being resisted by oil majors. This is blowing up into the biggest confrontation between the Chinese SOEs and oil majors (the biggest stake is held by Shell, followed by Exxon-Mobil, Chevron, and last TotalfinaELF) in Africa and around the world.

In the Democratic Republic of Congo, (DRC) China has replaced Belgium, the former imperialist power. In 2007 it made a massive deal to build infrastructure for copper, cobalt and nickel (mining?) in the infamous Katanga region. China has done a political deal with Kabila for this major joint venture. See especially the China DRC Coltan connection! As for who wins from these deals, according to one energy analyst’s blog, China wins.

In Ghana, China’s CNOOC has done a deal the GNPC (the state oil company) for oil exploration to develop its oil potential. A long relationship, technical assistance, JVs dam and telecoms, fisheries are a distant second to Britain FDI (143m cf 4.3 b) but it has the most projects. Thus Britain has big FDI stock in Ghana, but China’s policy is to develop oil production. This has brought it into conflict with Exxon-Mobil over who wins the support the Ghana state oil company.

In South Africa the global recession has made China the biggest trading partner, 50% bigger than the US which is No 2. Imports from China have grown 10 times since 2000. SA has a trade surplus with China. China has important interests in Sudan, Uganda and is facing intense rivalry with Anglo/US interests in Zimbabwe.

There is a debate in the liberal left about whether China’s interests in Africa (and elsewhere) are beneficial to the partner countries:

“International audiences are beginning to recognize the geopolitical significance of the recently burgeoning relationship between Africa and China, but there has been scant scholarly research concerning the realities and implications of this alignment, particularly from the African perspective. This paper offers a preliminary examination of whether the enhanced relations between Africa and China do, in fact, achieve "equality and mutual benefit." Or, do the pre-existing political, economic, and strategic inequalities between China and African states result in relations that are characterized by neocolonialism, dependence, and African insecurity?”

The Bolivarian left has also taken different positions. The Green Left takes the view that China is a maquiladora getting raw materials for the benefit of the foreign imperialists who produce for export in China:

“Chinese-owned companies’ investments in Africa are largely driven by a basic agenda of seeking fuel and minerals inputs for the production in China of manufactures by Chinese firms working as subcontractors for big Western corporations, with the bulk of the profits going to the latter. In 2002, exports by Chinese subsidiaries of First World corporations accounted for 25.8% of China’s exports — up from 20.3% in 1997, according to the World Investment Report 2006. According to the WIR 2006, the value added in China by the subsidiaries of First World corporations amounted to US$103.6 billion, and their pre-tax profits from such operations totalled $22.7 billion.”

Disagreeing with Chavez and his left cheerleaders the Green Left, James Petras (a critical supporter of Chavez) says that China is an “emerging imperialist power”:

“China’s ruling class, its outward billion dollar investments in western capitalist enterprises via its sovereign wealth funds, its billion dollar investments in overseas extractive enterprises, is driven by the mass of capital accumulated that is extracted via intense levels of labor exploitation and the elimination of state funded pensions, health plans and education. China’s role as an emerging imperial power is rooted in the imbalance between global power and social welfare decay. The fact that western capitalist writers, policymakers and their academic camp followers point to the same social imbalances in China as its domestic working class critics should not obscure a basic point. The Wall Street critics are defending the AFA financial elite against China’s export industrialists’ greater productivity; while the domestic working class critics are criticizing the capitalists and the state for their high rates of exploitation and concentration of wealth.”

Of course China and its partners promote the benefits of soft loans and infrastructure deals for the ‘development’ of Africa as distinct from the old colonizers. However the Financial Times points to China offering “cash” and getting “bargains”. For example China’s deal in the Congo is said to be more profitable than Freeport - the US world No 1 giant copper miner:

“The Chinese stand to gain in several ways from the deal as announced. In addition to their nearly $1.8 billion in annual profit from the mine, they’ll earn perhaps $4.5 billion in interest on the development loans—more if they carry an interest rate higher than two percent. There also looms the very large question of who will get the profits from the contracts to build the promised infrastructure. My assumption is that China's Sinohydro Corp and China Railway Engineering Corp will be awarded those contracts on a no-bid basis, which means they’ll take home another billion or so in profits on the project.”

If China can extract more profits than Freeport then it is clearly competing here as an imperialist power, not a proxy for the US or any other imperialist powers, or with ‘humanitarian’ or ‘socialist’ motives. Thus China is competing with Big Oil (Exxon, Shell etc) in Nigeria and getting hostile responses from other imperialist powers. It has sold arms to many countries, such as Zimbabwe, and has made huge loans to military regimes such as that of Guinea which are hardly out of concern for the wellbeing of the African masses.

China’s hardnosed investment explains why the US and other imperialist powers see China as an emerging rival. The US AFRICOM is reported as being set up in part to contain China’s moves in Africa. This would seem to be backed up by the fact that while it is based in Ghana (as a ‘democracy’) AFRICOM is training African armies in Uganda, Congo and Senegal. AFRICOM is also in Kinshasa training journalists, military, and MPs on how to use the press to advance policy in an area where China has its biggest mining investments in the DRC. We can safely say that the US military presence in Africa is to protect its interests facing growing competition from China’s expansion on that continent:

“An understanding of US interests is crucial for Ghana if it is to capitalise on the immense opportunity provided by the President Obama's July visit, writes Asare Otchere-Darko. Following a deepwater oil find in 2007, Ghana's pending oil-rich status has made it the subject of strategic US energy and military interests, and raising the stakes of Ghana-US relations, Otchere-Darko argues. As the US's preferred physical location for the US African Command (AFRICOM) headquarters and with the superpower concerned not to cede strategic ground to China in the region, Ghana has an unprecedented hand to play in this round of international diplomacy.”

The Battle for Latin America

Latin America is the third area of inter-imperialist conflict between the two blocs. The recent coup in Honduras proves that it is not the conflict between the US and France or Spain that is central to LA inter-imperialist rivalry, but that between the US and China. It’s clear that China is involved in every aspect of LA politics because its cash and its demand for commodities are keeping LA afloat during the crisis. China’s JVs with Bolivarian regimes played a role in the removal of Honduras president Zelaya. (It is also important to note that the IFLT’s position that the coup was staged to prepare a military offensive against Cuba, thus restore capitalism by military means, was also behind the coup). It was cheap Venezuelan oil that made Zelaya convert from a right-wing US backer to a ‘Bolivarian’ triggering his removal. Venezuela can afford to offer cheap oil because its oil production is underwritten by China’s huge demand and multi-billion dollar investments.

For the US the Bolivarian threat is tied to China’s ascendancy and its growing influence in Latin America. The US ruling class recognizes the reality of competition with China. It is a zero sum game. We cannot explain this as a disturbance caused by agreements between semi-colonies, or of China acting as a proxy for the US. If this was the case then the US would have nothing to fear from the growing influence of China in the US backyard. And unlike Chavez we don’t see China and Venezuela “marching towards socialism” together so the real threat is not a Bolivarian scenario of a global state socialist bloc:

“Hugo Chavez says he admires the libertarian legacy of the People's Republic of China, adding that the Asian giant can count on Venezuela as a friend. In a message to Chinese President Hu Jintao on the 60th anniversary of the People's Republic of China, Venezuelan president Chavez said that "we are marching towards socialism. In the name of the revolutionary spirit that unites us, we congratulate the honorable Chinese people and celebrate by its side its unbreakable will to emerge as a free and sovereign nation. To celebrate this popular victory is to say, the Chinese people have stood up," Chavez said in a statement. He underlined the "infinite admiration" he has for an event that "encourages global revolutions."

Chavez said that China has given ample evidence "that you do not need to be an empire in order to be a great power."

We don’t agree with Chavez that it is possible to be a “great power” without being an “empire”. Therefore to make sense of China’s rise in Latin America we have to understand both its imperialist expansion, and the role of the Bolivarians to provide a cover for this. This, by the way, explains Chavez’s support of the current regime in Iran). Hugo Restall writes in China’s "Latin American Gambit":

“Americans tend to see China's economic rise through the prism of the bilateral trade deficit and competition for manufacturing jobs. But the real story is that Chinese institutions are buying equity stakes and making loans to increase their influence in natural resources. And Latin America is the most important arena for China's investments. Some observers portray this as a threat in the U.S. "backyard." The truth is that the developing trade between China and Latin American countries represents an opportunity—if the U.S. plays its cards right. There are several reasons to be relatively sanguine about China's increasing involvement in Latin America. Most obviously, the Chinese interest in the region is pragmatic rather than ideological. The goal is to further economic growth at home by opening new markets and guaranteeing a supply of necessary inputs… The more China invests, moreover, the greater the risk of an eventual backlash. Already there are murmurings from vested interests in Latin countries that Beijing is a neocolonial power, buying raw materials and flooding the region with its cheap manufactured goods. Certainly competition from Chinese goods has had a much greater effect in Latin America than in the U.S., hurting the textile industries in Brazil, Argentina and Mexico. This has brought a wave of antidumping suits.”

In "Deals help China expand sway in Latin America" the authors write:

“As Washington tries to rebuild its strained relationships in Latin America, China is stepping in vigorously, offering countries across the region large amounts of money while they struggle with sharply slowing economies, a plunge in commodity prices and restricted access to credit. In recent weeks, China has been negotiating deals to double a development fund in Venezuela to $12 billion, lend Ecuador at least $1 billion to build a hydroelectric plant, provide Argentina with access to more than $10 billion in Chinese currency and lend Brazil’s national oil company $10 billion. The deals largely focus on China locking in natural resources like oil for years to come. China’s trade with Latin America has grown quickly this decade, making it the region’s second largest trading partner after the United States. But the size and scope of these loans point to a deeper engagement with Latin America at a time when the Obama administration is starting to address the erosion of Washington’s influence in the hemisphere.”

The Economist, in The Dragon in the Backyard argues that while China’s influence is still small, it is becoming a major trading and investment partners with Brazil, Venezuela, and Ecuador:

“Chinese investment has so far been overwhelmingly concentrated in mining and oil. (An early and still unusual exception is a joint venture with Brazil, dating from the 1980s, to produce communications satellites, in which China provides 70% of the finance and the technology.) Toromocho is just one of three big investments in copper projects in Peru. Chinese companies have become the biggest foreign investors in Ecuador’s oil industry. But it is China’s stake in Hugo Chávez’s Venezuela that is potentially most contentious. The China Development Bank has lent two-thirds of the capital for a $12 billion joint fund which Chinese companies could tap for investment projects in Venezuela. Most of these are likely to be in oil: CNPC, a Chinese company, is operating several smallish oilfields and is investing in the Orinoco tar sands. The United States has long been the main foreign market for Venezuelan oil. Venezuela provides about 10% of American oil imports, and Petróleos de Venezuela (PDVSA), the state oil monopoly, owns Citgo, an American oil distributor which has several refineries specially adapted to process the country’s heavy and sulphurous crude. This mutual dependence has long been a discomfort to Mr Chávez, and he has repeatedly said that he wants to divert Venezuelan oil to China (though transport costs would be much higher). So far Venezuelan oil exports to China have risen from a negligible level to 398,000 b/d. But PDVSA has announced that it wants to increase the flow to 500,000 b/d by December. That could be done only by reducing shipments to the United States.”

The US is concerned about rise of China (and Iran) in its backyard:
“Secretary of State Clinton told a meeting of State Department officers:
"What we are doing hasn’t worked very well and in fact, if you look at the gains, particularly in Latin American, that Iran is making and China is making, it is quite disturbing. Of course, there will be political and economic competition, even between the closest of allies”. But Clinton whipped out some Cold War memories to warn of a new Axis of Challenge: “We are looking at how to deal with [Nicaraguan President Daniel] Ortega. The Iranians are building a huge embassy in Managua. You can only imagine what it’s for.” This seems to be a bit of posturing, balancing President Obama’s recent appearance at the Summit of the Americas, but it does raise the question: if Washington wants to frame relations with Latin America as a battle with outside powers, how exactly does it propose to wage the political contest?”

China and US competition in Latin America is heating up but the US will not be overtaken by China in Latin America anytime soon:

“Ten-fold growth is stunning, but how does it compare to the champ? US-Latin American trade last year was US$560 billion, four times more than Sino-Latin trade. European-Latin American trade stood at US$280 billion, twice as much. In addition, with foreign investment in Latin America, China will not pass the US anytime soon. US companies invested US$350 billion in Latin America and the Caribbean in 2007, compared to only US$22 billion by Chinese firms… Regardless of who you have your money on, if the US and China are locked in for a title bout over Latin America, we’re only in round one.”

A research paper on China’s energy policy in Latin America makes the same point in terms of China’s economic performance. It focuses on the small size and limited growth of China’s interests. It concludes:

“While there is a select group of elected officials and scholars who believe China to be an imminent threat to American interests in the region, the prevailing opinion is one of cautious optimism. Deepening Sino-Latin American ties are a natural consequence of China’s economic development and should not be interpreted as aggressive or imperialistic behavior. Moreover, China is at a competitive disadvantage compared to the U.S. when it comes to the region. Throughout this paper we demonstrate that although a number of Chinese-owned energy concerns have struck deals across Latin America, the size and scope of these agreements is actually quite limited. In addition the technical demands of extracting Latin American oil, difficulties involved in transporting resources largely located near the Atlantic to the Pacific coast, limits placed on foreign involvement in most Latin American states, and domestic politics all curb China's ability to exploit the region's energy reserves. A final complicating factor for China is that her industrialization threatens manufacturing in many energy-producing states. In short, while China’s energy interests in Latin America have increased as of late, there are a plethora of factors that will likely prevent a significant Chinese presence for the foreseeable future. Our findings have important implications for those who conceive energy security in the region as a zero-sum game—where every barrel of oil obtained by the Chinese is one less barrel for the United States. This model drastically oversimplifies a globalized world, and furthermore, seems to presuppose an American claim to all energy resources on the planet. Reflexive Cold War era thinking, that replaces ideology with energy and prescribes that the U.S. prevent the Latin American dominoes from falling once again, is not only empirically inaccurate but dangerous and counterproductive. China is not the semi-autarkic Soviet Union. As perhaps confirmed by the current recession, the economic well being of China and the U.S. depends on a healthy American export market buttressed in part by Chinese debt financing. Since accessible and affordable energy are part and parcel of economic growth, China and the U.S. necessarily have a stake in each other’s energy security. These economic and energy interdependencies should be cultivated so that the costs of conflict rise and China is further integrated into the status quo. The decline of fossil fuel resources is a global problem requiring collaborative solutions. China, the U.S., and Latin America can all jointly benefit from the development of the region’s energy reserves if it is done so in a way that is transparent, market driven, and sustainable. The American government can help ensure this by revitalizing diplomatic relations with its Southern neighbors and encouraging the improvement of democratic institutions. Continued Sino-American dialogue regarding one another’s interests and intents in the region will also keep potentially hazardous misunderstandings and misperceptions to a minimum (Paz, 2006). Finally, the U.S. and China must start to think long-term about global energy needs and begin cooperating on alternative fuel technologies. For if Latin America ever becomes ground zero in an energy conflict between the two powers, everyone involved will have already lost.”

We agree that China is not yet a major economic threat to the US in its own backyard, and is more likely to expand at the expense of Spain and France or in collaboration with them. But the above analysis downplays as alarmist the strategic partnership that China and the Bolivarian states have established. China by itself is not the only issue – there is also the global bloc of which it is the leading member.

In Latin America, Venezuela is the key to this geo-strategic bloc between the Bolivarian states and China leading Brazil, Bolivia, Argentina, Ecuador and Chile. As one article headlines, it’s an Axis of Oil. China and the Bolivarians are very keen to present China’s influence in Latin America as benign and as the progressive alternative to US imperialism interested in ‘development’:

"China now wants to show it is a responsible stakeholder in the region," says Dan Erikson, a specialist in China-Latin American relations from the Inter-American Dialogue. "It has the image in Latin America of being 'mercantilist', or only interested in taking out commodities. Now it wants to show it is interested in Latin America's longer-term development."

But as in Asia and Africa China is not only interested in trade. Where it can, it buys up or invests in energy production. For example, a new deal with Venezuela for 16 billion (following one with Russia for $20 b) is for exploration and production of oil in the Orinoco. China’s CNPC is part of a JV with Total (France) and three Japanese firms including Mitsubishi, in the Orinoco. Total stayed in Venezuela after the oil renationalization whereas Exxon left. Total has a presence in China itself so this shows that French and Chinese imperialism are collaborating not only in Latin America but also in China itself. Typically Venezuela has signed a railroad deal with China.

Moreover, China is doing cash for oil swaps as in Brazil where it recently did a deal with Petrobras the SOE for $10 billion cash for 10 years of oil. Petrobras will use this cash to help develop its new offshore reserves. The Bolivarians will say that China is lending money to an SOE which uses part of its profits for ‘development’.

Petrobras entered into a deal with Bolivia’s Morales to split the profits of its big gas extraction in that country. Was this ‘development’ or super-exploitation? It suits the Bolivarians to present China as a benign giant without imperialist interests because this helps to cover up their own role as junior partners of all imperialist countries. Lula’s Petrobras enters JVs with the oil majors like (the French) Totalfina to develop its oilfields. They get their super profits. Morales’ YPFB (SOE) gets its profits from JVs and oil majors like (the Spanish) Repsol.

The fact that the Venezuelan, Brazilian and Bolivian state owned oil companies are key players only means that they serve the interests of imperialism as their junior state bourgeois partners. In the case of China however, the SOEs do not serve the interests of the oil majors but the interests of the Chinese imperialist bourgeoisie. This is because they can export their finance capital in the form of huge cash for oil deals and act as the backers of the Bolivarian regimes, bankrolling JVs and taking oil and other minerals in return. Another example is the offer to buy Repsol YPFs majority stake in the Argentinian YPF for $17 billion.

Crisis, Revolution and Counter-Revolution

To summarise, the distinguishing feature of the current crisis is not merely that the global crisis has opened a new period of increasing rivalry between existing imperialist powers under the domination of the US, but is one in which China (supported by Russia) as former workers states have entered the stage and now potentially challenge the hegemony of the dominant US imperialism and its supporting powers. This is the fundamental feature of the current crisis that distinguishes it from the depression of the 1930s when the US in order to defeat its rivals had to do deals with the USSR, and the onset of the structural crisis of overproduction in the 1970s when both Russia and China were still outside the global capitalist economy.

The minority, however, does not say that the US stopped being a main engine of the world economy. While China is clearly a new rising imperialist power, it cannot replace the US as the dominating power without an all-out war against the US which will bring a massive destruction of the productive forces and barbarism. China can challenge the US via economic competition only to a certain point. In other words, a replacement of the US as the main power cannot happen without a (nuclear) Third-World-War which will result in a massive destruction of the planet and the human race. It is only the socialist revolution that can stop such catastrophic developments.

Today’s crisis follows the capitalist restoration of these states, which far from becoming new semi-colonies allowing US imperialism to remain unchallenged in is global hegemony, have turned into potential rivals competing with the US over access to critical raw materials. Already the beginnings of this rivalry between these two blocs have spilled over into proxy wars in Georgia, the intensification of the war in Afghanistan and Pakistan for control of Central Asia, and mounting trade protection and military buildups (Africom).

Furthermore, the downloading of this crisis onto the workers of the weakest imperialisms and their colonies and semi-colonies will pose the alternative of socialism or barbarism with a renewed sharpness and urgency. We have seen this already in Palestine, Iraq, Greece, Guadeloupe, Peru, and Honduras. It is pushing the masses in the Middle East, Africa and Latin America to the point of insurrection. In the stronger imperialist powers, there is no way out for the ruling class without inter-imperialist wars, and civil wars against their own proletariat. With these developments the question of power is posed or will be posed in the near future.

The role of the treacherous leaders of the working class grouped together in the WSF and led by the restorationist Castro bureaucracy together with the Bolivarian bourgeoisies, represents the main barrier to the mobilization of the worlds’ workers on the revolutionary road. Their brand of reformism is a recycling of the old Menshevik/Stalinist popular front and two stage program of first the national revolution, and then socialism. Today it is branded as Bolivarian or “21st century socialism”. Its role is to tie the hands of workers in democratic fronts in collaboration with the Bolivarian bourgeoisies and China as a “great power” against “US imperialism”. This is the road to counter-revolution. The defeat of the world’s workers at the hands of the Castroites and the Bolivarians backed by China and Russia must be prevented at all costs by the regroupment of healthy Trotskyist and revolutionary workers to form a new World Party of Socialism.

The strategic task for revolutionary Trotskyists is to use their analysis of the current situation to regroup the vanguard to fight back against all the counter-revolutionary attacks and wars of the imperialists, and to rebuild the World Party of Socialism founded by Trotsky in 1938 as a new revolutionary international capable of providing the revolutionary leadership that the working class needs and deserves in the struggle for world socialist revolution.

Communist Workers Group (New Zealand)
Humanist Workers for Revolutionary Socialism (US)

October 2009